Mechanics of Mining Rewards

July 21, 2024 by Alan Szepieniec

Concept art.
Fig.1.: Mechanics of mining reward distribution. Imagination by Perchance.

Mechanics of Mining Rewards

The distribution of mining rewards is conceptually simple, but certain architectural decisions in Neptune make the concrete mechanics of this process rather challenging to specify and implement. This note articulates the problems that arise and motivates the solutions we came up with.

Concept

The limit on Neptune's token supply, 42 million units, is as good as set in stone1. These coins come into existence through mining, which is the process of binding proof-of-work with a selection of transactions in order to establish consensus on their finality. Miners are rewarded for this task in two ways:

  1. The block subsidy is distributed to a spending address, or collection of spending addresses, under their control.
  2. The transaction fees with which transaction initiators prioritize their own transactions.

Where the transactions only redistribute existing coins, the block subsidy mints new ones. Almost all coins come into existence through block subsidies – and if the term "block subsidy" covers the premine, then this statement is true for all coins.

The supply is limited because the magnitude of the subsidy is automatically reduced in accordance with an exponential decay curve. As a result, the total sum of all block subsidies ever is finite, and if you include the premine in that sum, the total is exactly 42 million.

To avoid any doubt it is worth reiterating a second feature that is also as good as set in stone. The premine consists of 1.98% of the supply limit, or 831600 coins. They are allocated to persons who made the project possible prior to launch.

Challenges

While the conceptual framework of Neptune's mining rewards is straightforward, several practical challenges arise when implementing this system.

  1. Two-step mining. To produce a block, a miner must both a) prove its correctness, and b) solve a proof-of-work puzzle.
  2. Time-locked mining reward. Of entire block reward, i.e., subsidy plus fees, only half is immediately liquid. The remainder is released after three years.
  3. Dynamic block intervals. If the protocol observes good network conditions, short proving times, and full blocks, the target block interval is automatically reduced.

Two-Step Mining

Mining consists of two steps.

  1. Proving. The miner produces a STARK proof of the correctness of the block body, ensuring that the transaction is valid and that the previous block (body and header) was also valid. Proving is a labor-intensive task requiring tens of gigabytes of RAM and either several dozen CPU cores or a GPU. It is difficult to parallelize, meaning that the prover with the faster hardware has a consistent advantage in producing the proof first. The motivation for including the block proof is protocol succinctness, which is the non-reliance on more-than-negligible amounts of historical blockchain data for evaluating the fork choice rule. Specifically, in order to decide which of two contender blocks is canonical, Neptune nodes need no information besides those contender blocks and the common hash of the genesis block. The blocks' correctness proofs establish that they are both valid descendants of the genesis block and that their advertised aggregate proof of work numbers were computed correctly. Evaluating the fork choice rule involves verifying the proofs and comparing these numbers. As a result, nodes can synchronize to the network in milliseconds, without trust assumptions, and with the same robustness as if they had verified all of history.
  2. Preimage search. A block header contains, among other things, random data often called a nonce2. Consequently, the hash digest of the block is hard to predict without computing the hash function. The preimage search involves sampling this random data in the hope that the resulting block digest is smaller than a target difficulty. If this condition is met, then the miner has found a new block which, when broadcast, will likely be accepted by peers as the new tip of the canonical chain. Preimage search is stateless, and therefore this step is a Poisson process allocating the expectation of success to searchers in proportion to their hash rate. It is also embarrassingly parallelizable, meaning that the searcher with the cheaper electricity bill (whether due to energy-efficient hardware or availability of cheap electricity) has a marginal advantage over the searcher with the more expensive one. All other things equal, preimage search favors searchers with access to cheap electricity. The geographical distribution of cheap power is the physical decentralization that underpins the virtual decentralization of the cryptocurrency that utilizes it.

The challenge arises because proving is stateful and breaks the Poisson nature of mining. In a naïve implementation, the miner with the faster hardware has a consistent head start over the slower miner in the preimage search step, leading to a distribution of mining power that biased away from the decentralized distribution of cheap energy and towards something that is emphatically not decentralized. Worse still, the advantage of fast provers constitutes a strong centralizing force in the evolution of mining pools.

The physics of power consumption in processors is the relevant constraint. The power consumed by a chip grows polynomially3 with the frequency. Therefore, a miner who buys twice as much hardware running at half the frequency will consume less power while computing the same number of hashes. In a Poisson mining environment, this trade-off benefits the miner because his electricity cost is less and his reward is the same. As a consequence, miners prefer energy-efficient hardware, and over time the distribution of mining power will tend to match the distribution of cheap energy. In contrast, in a stateful mining environment, this trade-off makes no sense because while the miner's power consumption is reduced, so is his expectation of mining rewards. Consequently, for the same power budget, miners prefer fewer units of faster hardware over more units of energy-efficient hardware. The optimal configuration is one chip per power source, and ultimately some power sources are too small to be competitive while large power sources can justify acquiring the ultra-high-end chip. This economy of scale punishes small power sources and rewards large ones even when the price per kilowatt-hour is the same.

This deficiency is addressed by splitting the block reward into two parts. The prover, who assembles a block and proves its correctness but does not participate in the preimage search, chooses which portion of the block reward to allocate to himself. The remainder of the block reward goes to the searcher who completes the block by finding the right randomness in the header such that the block hash is small enough.

Fast provers can allocate to themselves a large portion of the block reward. Slow provers can compete only by shrinking the allocated block reward. Searchers will rationally switch to whichever block leaves the largest reward for the searcher, and so they should constantly test announced block proposals to see if the searcher reward is larger. The premium for fast proven-but-unworked block proposals will tend to equal the advantage that the corresponding head start gives in the searching step.

This dynamic benefits from an example. Suppose we have a configuration of provers $1, 2, 3, \ldots$ with proof times $(t_1, t_2, t_3, \ldots)$ as a fraction of the target block interval and satisfying $t_1 < t_2 < t_3 < \ldots$. And suppose the claimed prover rewards as a fraction of the total block reward are $(c_1, c_2, c_3, \ldots)$. Furthermore, let $(s_1, s_2, s_3, \ldots)$ be the fractions of the searching population for which it is economical to search on top of a block proposal where respectively a fraction $(c_1, c_2, c_3, \ldots)$ of the block reward is claimed by the prover. In this environment:

  • Before block proposal 1 is broadcasted, searchers can do nothing.
  • When block proposal 1 is broadcasted, a fraction $s_1$ of the total searching power will switch on.
  • In general, when the $n$ th proven-but-unworked block proposal is published, the existing population of searchers will rationally switch to the new proposal, and a fraction $s_n - s_{n-1}$ will switch on.
  • The probability $P_n$ that a block is found in the time period $(t_n; t_{n+1})$ is approximately4 proportional to the total number of hashes computed in that period, which is proportional to the product of the duration with the active proportion of searching power: $P_n \propto (t_{n+1}-t_n) \cdot s_n$.
  • The prover's reward is proportional to this number and to the claimed portion, so $(t_{n+1}-t_n) \cdot s_n \cdot c_n$.
  • The proportion of searching power $s_n$ is a monotonically decreasing function of the proportion of the reward claimed $c_n$, so there is some $c_n$ which maximizes the miner's expectation of profit. Above this maximum, too few searchers will switch on. Below this maximum, the prover could have charged more.
  • As a first-order approximation and all other variables remaining equal, if prover $n$ reduces his proof generation time to $t_n - \epsilon$ then he can command $1 + \frac{\epsilon}{t_{n+1}-t_n}$ times as much profit. Whether the increased profit justifies purchasing the hardware (and perhaps also software) needed to produce proofs that much faster depends on the cost of that capital investment.

Is there room for malicious behavior? It is difficult to analyze all possible deviations from the protocol but the following behaviors come to mind at first thought.

  1. Searchers decline to switch to a proven-but-unworked block proposal whose searcher share is larger. In isolation, this strategy is costly. In combination with a colluding prover, it might make sense if the bribe from the prover outweighs the advantage of switching. This scenario is identical to the prover reducing the prover reward, and increasing the searcher reward, by the equivalent amount.
  2. Provers decline to broadcast proven-but-unworked block proposals. In isolation, this strategy is costly. In combination with a colluding searcher (or collection of searchers) if the prover gets a bribe from them for keeping the proposal from all other searchers. This scenario is identical to the prover increasing the prover reward, and decreasing the searching reward, by the equivalent amount.
  3. Provers charge out-of-market prices. The market price is precisely the price that optimizes for profit, so provers that follow this strategy necessarily incur a cost.
  4. Mining pools, wherein one centralized operator produces the proof and subscribers contribute searching power. This strategy is certainly rational for searchers looking to reduce the variance on their rewards. And since there is a demand for reduced variance, there is a potential profit for pool operators, all other things equal. Since there is no mechanism for operators to lock in subscribers, they are bound to either charging market prices (up to a fee for variance reduction) for their proofs or incurring a loss. The incentive for searchers to join the bigger pool must come from a loss on the part of the pool operator relative to just publishing his block proposal in the same time without administering the pool. Commanding a larger army of subscribers who contribute searching power can justify the loss incurred to acquire it, but this dynamic has an identical counterpart in single-step mining architectures such as Bitcoin. It follows that two-step mining introduces no new centralization hazard to the mining pool environment.

A second challenge arises from the possibility that the searcher is a different party from the prover. The block reward needs to be distributed to distinct addresses. However, the block proof only pertains to the block body and not the header, because searching involves modifying part of the block (the header) without invalidating the proof. The prover does not know in advance who will be the winning searcher, and so the searcher's address for receiving his block reward cannot possibly be in the block body.

The solution is to populate the randomness in the block header with this data. Specifically, instead of a nonce field, the block header in Neptune has a receiver_digest field5 and a lock_script_hash field. The next block is responsible for assembling coinbase UTXOs (one timelocked and one without locks) destined for the winning searcher.

In the context of a mining pool with hundreds of subscribers contributing searching power, these two fields are inadequate for distributing rewards to more than one searcher. However, the mining pool operator, who assembles a block and proves its correctness, can claim a large prover reward and distribute it in the block body to all subscribers in proportion to their search power contribution.

Time-Locked Mining Reward

The entire block reward is split into two parts, orthogonal to the miner-searcher split. The first part constitutes 25% of the block reward and is liquid immediately (or as soon as possible in the case of the searcher's reward). The remaining 75% is time-locked for three years and becomes spendable at that point. This time lock ensures that miners' incentives are aligned with the project's long-term success.

The prover's portion of the block reward is encapsulated as two UTXOs (one timelocked and one without locks), both of which are listed as explicit outputs of the block's transaction. (Recall that the block has only one transaction, which represents the merger of all transactions that the miner (and in fact: prover) decided to confirm.) Also listed as explicit outputs of the block's transaction are the UTXOs associated with the previous block's searcher's reward. The block proof establishes, among other things, that all the amounts, as well as the time locks, are correct.

Dynamic Block Intervals

The protocol automatically adjusts the target difficulty so that blocks are found at an expected rate equal to a target block interval. The protocol furthermore tracks the block orphan rate. A low block orphan rate indicates good network conditions resulting in little power wasted on blocks that end up losing a block race. When the orphan rate is low and has been for a sustained period of time, the network can tolerate either larger blocks or more frequent ones.

Besides the block orphan rate, the protocol also tracks an estimate of the block proving time and the fullness of blocks. If the orphan rate is low, blocks are full, and the proving time is small (relative to the block time), the target block interval is lowered. If the orphan rate is low, blocks are full, and the proving time is large, the block size bound is increased.

To track these signals in a way that is compatible with protocol succinctness – meaning that we do not have access to a large window of recent blocks – Neptune uses exponential moving averages. Specifically, the header contains values that are updated with every block according to the formula $x \mapsto \alpha \cdot x + (1 - \alpha) \cdot s$, where $\alpha$ is a smoothing parameter determining how quickly the signal-tracker adapts to changes in the signal it tracks; and $s$ is the signal itself, which could be

  • the number of orphans observed since the last block; or
  • the ratio between the block's size and its size bound; or
  • the difference between the current block's timestamp and the previous, adjusted for proving time by subtracting the proving time tracker; or adjusted for searching time by subtracting the target block interval.

The capability for the target block interval to drop makes the question about the block time moot; and it is also the reason why the follow-up question about the block subsidy is impossible to give a straight answer to. The block reward must depend on the target block interval because otherwise the issuance schedule of new coins is broken.

Neptune defines a base interval, which is a fixed time interval; and a base subsidy, which is as number of coins that is reduced every epoch independently of variable network parameters. Furthermore, a variable called the acceleration factor, which for convenience is always a power of two and initially set to 1, determines the concrete block interval and concrete subsidy simply by dividing the the base interval and base subsidy by it. If the protocol reduces the target block interval, it does so by doubling the acceleration factor.

Conclusion

This article covers three features impacting Neptune's block reward distribution. To the best of our knowledge, Neptune is the first blockchain featuring two-step mining and partially time-locked block rewards. And while dynamic block times and sizes already exist, Neptune is the first to marry this feature with protocol succinctness. These novel features induce challenges for implementing the block reward distribution mechanism, but ultimately these challenges can be resolved through clever architecture and engineering.

That said, present tense notwithstanding, this article is the first or maybe second step in the architecture and engineering process. At the time of writing, these features and the mechanisms for achieving them have not been implemented yet. The good news is that you get to play a part in their realization – if you want.

Acknowledgements. Thanks to danda for fruitful discussions.

1

In the present context, the phrase "as good as set in stone" means "exceedingly unlikely to change given previous public statements and promises". As for for the other features alluded to in this note – take them with a grain of salt as they might change between now and launch, or be postponed until Hard Fork One.

2

The choice of word is objectionable because it breaks with its origin in the cryptographic literature where it connotes a norm that one should not ever, under any circumstances, reuse the same nonce. This norm does not apply in the context of proof-of-work.

3

The power dissipation equation $P = C V^2 f$ is of course correct but misleading because the frequency that you can run a chip at depends on the voltage.

4

This approximation holds for small periods and small fractions of searching power, but is inaccurate in general because the probabilities of events in a disjunction cannot be added. However, failures to find blocks are independent events whose probabilities can be multiplied. Let $p$ be the probability of single hash trial resulting in a valid block, then $1-P_n = (1-p)^{(t_{n+1}-t_n)\cdot s_n \cdot c}$, where $c$ is the total hash power in terms of number of hashes per unit of time. So, the logarithm of the probability of not finding a block in time period $(t_n; t_{n+1})$ is proportional to the number of hashes computed in that period: $\log (1-P_n) = (t_{n+1}-t_n) \cdot s_n \cdot c \cdot \ln (1-p)$. Recall the Taylor series of $\ln (1-x) \approx -x - \frac{x^2}{2} - \frac{x^3}{3} \ldots$ which converges for $x \in [-1;1)$. Ignoring higher order terms gives $P_n \propto (t_{n+1}-t_n) \cdot s_n$ as an approximation.

5

The receiver_digest field does not identify the recipient (or in this case, the miner); instead, it is a requirement of the mutator set which serves precisely to protect their anonymity. In order to spend the UTXO the recipient will need to derive data from the preimage of the receiver_digest – and prove the integrity of this derivation in zero knowledge.